Introduction

Agency problems arise in any environment involving principal–agent relationships. Following the theory of agency, if the principal hopes to ensure that the agent will make decisions that are optimal for the principal rather than the agent themselves, the differing objectives of the pair make agency costs inevitable. This issue not only applies to firm ownership structure, but also to the political agency process. Numerous recent studies have analysed agency problems. Jensen and Meckling (1976) explain that agency costs arise in any environment without cooperation between agent and principal. Besley and Case (1995) demonstrate that the incumbent will improve his welfare by investing less effort, contradicting the objectives of voters. The marginal disutility of effort incurring agency costs can be resolved by the threats to the government’s re-election (see, e.g., Seabright, 1996). Belleflamme and Hindriks (2005) observe that yardstick competition between jurisdictions exerts both discipline and sorting effects within the political agency framework. Voters can mitigate agency costs below the Leviathan level by adopting a successful voting strategy (as noted by Wrede, 2001).

Dahlby (1996) has analysed agency problems for the case of fiscal externalities. Both direct and indirect fiscal externalities can be corrected by matching revenue, matching expenditure or equalisation grants devised by the state and federal governments. Within the vertical fiscal externalities framework, Dahlby and Wilson (2003) show that the jurisdictional government will underprovide or overprovide local public goods depending on the assumptions made. Furthermore, when one considers a model of fiscal federalism featuring both vertical and horizontal fiscal externalities, as Brülhart and Jametti (2019) have observed, tax competition can represent second-best efficient Leviathan taming by constraining the scope for public-sector revenue maximisation. Following Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986), local public goods provided by local governments are underprovided through interregional property tax competition. Therefore, if lump-sum tax cannot be operated by the local government, the under-provision of local public goods financed by the distortionary tax is inevitable in a standard model of tax competition. To solve this issue, it is often argued that an intergovernmental matching grant devised by the federal government can be introduced to ease the exorbitant marginal cost of local public funds deriving from the downward pressure on tax rates, assuming that the federal government is benevolent and omniscient (see, e.g., Dahlby, 1996).

In the discussion of the spillover effect of local public goods among jurisdictions, the prevailing view is that spillover will aggravate the under-provision of such goods (see e.g. Boadway et al., 1989). However, an alternative opinion on this problem is that the spillover effect of local public goods may alleviate the under-provision of such goods in some situations. Ogawa (2006) argues that the matching grant rate may decrease with spillover effect if the elasticity of capital with respect to the capital tax rate is significant in a tax competition model. Kawachi and Ogawa (2006) find that local governments are more inclined to provide local public goods efficiently given a sufficient spillover effect in a repeated-game model with large homogeneous jurisdictions.

The literature (see, e.g., Belleflamme and Hindriks, 2005; Besley and Case, 1995) emphasises agency problems and confirms that agency costs can raise the marginal cost of local public goods provided in jurisdictions. Consequently, jurisdictions will experience an undersupply of local public goods if the marginal benefit of local public funds is unaffected by a given issue. However, few studies deal with agency problems in situations involving horizontal tax externalities. One example of such a study is Nishigaki and Kato (2016), who show that yardstick competition in the small jurisdictions model generates additional costs of financing public goods and increases the seriousness of the under-provision of public goods caused by tax competition. In contrast to their approach, this paper finds that tax competition mitigates the under-provision of local public goods if agency costs are large enough. Accordingly, the optimal matching grant rate devised by the federal government should decrease with the intensiveness of tax competition, considering the large agency costs.

In this study, we introduce tax competition and benefit spillovers into the model to generalise the effect of horizontal fiscal externalities and benefit spillovers leading to under-provision of public goods on the agency cost problem.

This paper is organised as follows. The inefficiency of the agency cost problem in a closed economy with consumption spillover effect among jurisdictions is set out in the section “The model”. We introduce tax competition into the model in the section “The introduction of tax competition” to generalise the effect of horizontal fiscal externalities leading to under-provision of public goods on the agency cost problem. Finally, the section “Conclusion” draws conclusions.

The model

In this section, we start with the case where private capital is not mobile. There are n identical local jurisdictions, where each jurisdiction i (=1, 2, \(\ldots\), n) has a single immobile resident, and preferences are defined by a strictly quasi-concave utility function Ui(xi, Gi), where xi is the consumption of a private numeraire good and Gi is the local public good. The local public good consumption in jurisdiction i is defined by

$$G_i = g_i + \beta \mathop {\sum}\limits_{j \ne i} {g_j} ,$$
(1)

where gi is the provision of the local public good by the jurisdictional government i, and β (0 β 1) indicates the degree of benefit spillover. We assume that the jurisdictional governments are partly self-interested. Therefore, the welfare function of jurisdictional government i is written by Wi = Vi[Xi(gi)] + Ui(Gi, xi), where Vi[Xi(gi)] are the agency costs, with Vi[Xi(gi)] > 0, \(V_i^\prime\)[Xi(gi)] < 0, \(V_i^{\prime\prime}\)[Xi(gi)] < 0. Additionally, Xi(gi) denotes the variation in effort, which reflects differences in incumbent types, with Xi(gi) > 0, \(X_i^\prime\)(gi) > 0, \(X_i^{\prime\prime}\)(gi) > 0Footnote 1. Although the jurisdictional governments desire more excess rents, they must consider the utility of residents in their jurisdictions to ensure their own re-election and access to rents. However, the central government is assumed to be benevolent. For simplicity, we assume that the aggregate output is exogenous in each jurisdiction, and can be expressed by yi. The jurisdictional governments impose lump-sum taxes on the resident to fund local public good provision, and the central government imposes lump-sum taxes on the resident to fund the matching grant. The budget constraint of the resident is given by

$$x_i = y_i - z_i - h,$$
(2)

where zi is the lump-sum tax imposed by jurisdiction i and h is the tax imposed by central government, which is assumed to be identical for all jurisdictions. The budget constraint of the government of jurisdiction i can be given by

$$z_i + s_i = g_i,$$
(3)

where si is the matching grant the government of jurisdiction i receives from the central government. Hence, the matching grant si can be given by

$$s_i = mg_i,$$
(4)

where m is the rate of the uniform matching grant. We assume a uniform matching grant rate because the jurisdictions are homogeneous at the symmetric equilibriumFootnote 2. Fiscal revenue finances the provision of local public goods. In Eq. (2) h should satisfy the central government’s budget constraint, which is given by

$$\mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {s_i} = nh = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {mg_i} .$$
(5)

This model involves two stages:

In stage 1, the central government chooses national tax rate h and matching grant rate m.

In stage 2, the jurisdictional government i chooses local tax rate zi and local public good gi, taking h and m as given.

The central government cares about all individuals in the country, and wants to set m and h so as to realise efficient provision of local public goods by jurisdictional governments in a non-cooperative equilibrium, according to the Pareto-optimal condition derived below.

The jurisdictional government i wishes to maximise the objective function Wi subject to (1)–(4), taking the tax rates zj and the provision of local public goods of other jurisdictions gj as given. The maximisation problem is then defined as

$${}_{g_i,z_i}^{\mathrm {{max}}}W_i = V_i\left[ {X_i\left( {g_i} \right)} \right] + U_i(G_i,x_i)$$
(6)
$$\begin{array}{l}{\mathrm{s}}{\mathrm{.t}}{\mathrm{.}}\,x_i = y_i - z_i - {h}\\ z_i + s_i = g_i\\ s_i = {m}g_i\\ G_i = g_i + {\beta}\mathop {\sum}\limits_{j \ne i} {g_j} .\end{array}$$

We use the substitution method and differentiate Wi with respect to gi, and the first-order condition can be written asFootnote 3

$$\frac{{\partial W_i}}{{\partial g_i}} = V_i^\prime X_i^\prime + \frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial G_i}} - (1 - m)\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial x_i}} = 0.$$
(7)

We have considered all jurisdictions to be identical. That is, \(V_i^\prime X_i^\prime\) = \(V_j^\prime X_j^\prime\), \(\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial G_i}} = \frac{{\partial U_j}}{{\partial G_j}}\) and \(\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial x_i}} = \frac{{\partial U_j}}{{\partial x_j}}\). Therefore, Eq. (7) at the symmetric equilibrium can be rewritten as

$$V^\prime X^\prime + \frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial G}} - (1 - m)\frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial x}} = 0,$$
(8)

where the jurisdiction-specific subscripts i and j are omitted.

The Pareto-optimal condition, however, is derived by

$$\begin{array}{l}{}_{x_i,g_i}^{\mathrm {{max}}}\mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {U_i} \left( {i = 1,2, \ldots \ldots ,n} \right),\\ {\mathrm{s}}{\mathrm{.t}}{\mathrm{.}}\,\mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {x_i} + \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {g_i} = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {y_i} ,\end{array}$$

The Lagrange function is given by

$${L}\left( {g_i,x_i} \right) = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {U_i} + \lambda \left[ {\mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {x_i} + \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {g_i} - \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {y_i} } \right].$$

Differentiating L(gi, xi) with respect to gi and xi gives us

$$\begin{array}{l}\frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial g_i}} = \frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial G_i}} + {\beta}\mathop {\sum}\limits_{j \ne i} {\frac{{\partial U_j}}{{\partial G_j}}} + \lambda = 0,\\ \frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial x_i}} = \frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial x_i}} + \lambda = 0,\end{array}$$

which can be rewritten as

$$\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial G_i}} + {\beta}\mathop {\sum}\limits_{j \ne i} {\frac{{\partial U_j}}{{\partial G_j}}} = \frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial x_i}}.$$
(9)

We have considered all jurisdictions to be identical. Therefore, Eq. (9) at the symmetric equilibrium can be rewritten as

$$\left[ {1 + \beta \left( {n - 1} \right)} \right]\frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial G}} = \frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial x}},$$
(10)

where the jurisdiction-specific subscripts i and j are omitted.

Comparison of Eqs. (8) and (10) shows the optimal matching grant rate which the central government should choose is given byFootnote 4

$${m} = \frac{{\beta \left( {n - 1} \right)}}{{1 + \beta (n - 1)}} - \frac{{V^\prime X^\prime }}{{U_x}}.$$
(11)

Recalling that V′ < 0, X′ > 0, we know from Eq. (11) that the optimal matching grant rate increases with agency costs (∂m/∂VX′ < 0). Besides benefit spillovers, note that agency costs may also aggravate the under-provision of local public goods in the absence of tax competition among local jurisdictionsFootnote 5. This finding corresponds with conclusions from the literature (e.g., see Belleflamme and Hindriks, 2005; Besley and Case, 1995). Notably, this result is an extension of Boadway et al. (1989) and Ogawa (2006) with reference to a particular case.

The introduction of tax competition

Thus far, we have shown the inefficiency of the agency cost problem in a closed economy with consumption spillover effect among jurisdictions. However, in practice, private capital is movable among jurisdictions and jurisdictional governments can raise revenue only or partly via distortional capital taxes within their own jurisdictionsFootnote 6. Therefore, in the present study, we now rebuild the model of tax competition in which private capital is put into production and is perfectly mobile among jurisdictions, and jurisdictional governments raise revenue not with a lump-sum tax but rather a distortional capital taxFootnote 7.

As before, we assume n identical jurisdictions, where each jurisdiction i(=1, 2, …, n) has a single immobile resident providing the labour, li = 1. The production functions in all jurisdictions are identical, and the labour is not shown explicitly in those functions. That is, the production function in jurisdiction i is simply given by

$$y_i = f_i\left( {k_i^{\mathrm {p}}} \right),$$
(12)

where \(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}\) is the private capital in jurisdiction i. Private capital has perfect mobility. Therefore, in equilibrium the after-tax return to capital is equalised across jurisdictions

$$f_{kp}({k}_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - t_i = f_{kp}\left( {{k}_j^{\mathrm {p}}} \right) - t_j = r(j\, \ne \,i)$$
(13)

for all i(=1, 2, …, n), where fkp(\(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}\)) ≡ ∂fi(\(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}\))/∂\(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}\) > 0, fkpkp < 0, ti is the tax rate per unit of capital in jurisdiction i and r is the after tax return to private capital in the country.

The total supply of private capital in the country is fixed at \(\bar K^{\mathrm {p}}\) such that

$$\bar K^{\mathrm {p}} = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {k_i^{\mathrm {p}}} .$$
(14)

The budget constraint of the resident is as follows:

$$x_i = f_i(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - f_{kp}(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}){k}_i^{\mathrm {p}} + r\bar k_i^{\mathrm {P}} - h,$$
(15)

where \(\bar k_i^{\mathrm {P}}\) is the initial endowment of private capital in jurisdiction i and h is the lump-sum tax imposed by the central government. Substituting Eq. (13) into Eq. (15), Eq. (15) can be rewritten as

$$x_i = f_i(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - t_ik_i^{\mathrm {p}} + r(\bar k_i^{\mathrm {P}} - k_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - h.$$
(15')

The jurisdictional government budget constraint is given by

$$t_ik_i^{\mathrm {p}} + s_i = g_i.$$
(16)

As before, the jurisdictional government i receives a matching grant from the central government to provide the local public good. Hence, the following condition holds:

$$s_i = mg_i.$$
(17)

The lump-sum tax imposed by the central government h will be set to satisfy the budget constraint of the central government, as follows:Footnote 8

$$\mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {s_i} = nh = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {mg_i} .$$
(18)

This model involves two stages:

In stage 1, the central government chooses the national tax h and the matching grant rate m.

In stage 2, the jurisdictional government i chooses the local tax ti and the local public good gi, taking h and m as given.

The jurisdictional government i wishes to maximise the objective function Wi subject to Eqs. (13)–(17), taking the tax rates tj and the provision of local public goods of other jurisdictions gj as given. Then, the maximisation problem is defined as

$${}_{g_i,t_i}^{{\mathrm {max}}}W_i = V_i\left[ {X_i\left( {g_i} \right)} \right] + U_i(G_i,x_i),$$
(19)
$$\begin{array}{l}{\mathrm{s}}{\mathrm{.t}}{\mathrm{.}}\,f_{kp}({k}_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - t_i = f_{kp}\left( {{k}_j^{\mathrm {p}}} \right) - t_j = r,(j\, \ne \,i)\\ x_i = f_i(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}) - f_{kp}(k_i^{\mathrm {p}}){k}_i^{\mathrm {p}} + r\overline k _i^{\mathrm {p}} - h,\\ t_ik_i^{\mathrm {p}} + s_i = g_i,\\ s_i = {\mathrm{m}}g_i,\\ \bar K^{\mathrm {p}} = \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i = 1}^n {k_i^{\mathrm {p}}} .\end{array}$$

The first-order condition givesFootnote 9

$$\frac{{\partial W_i}}{{\partial t_i}} = \frac{1}{{1 - m}}V_i^\prime X_i^\prime \left( {k_i^{\mathrm {p}} + t_i\frac{{\partial k_i^{\mathrm {p}}}}{{\partial t_i}}} \right) + \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\frac{1}{{1 - m}}\left( {k_i^{\mathrm {p}} + t_i\frac{{\partial k_i^{\mathrm {p}}}}{{\partial t_i}} + \beta \mathop {\sum}\limits_{i \ne j} {t_j} \frac{{\partial k_j^{\mathrm {p}}}}{{\partial t_i}}} \right)\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial G_i}} + } \\ {\left[ { - k_i^{\mathrm {p}} + (\bar k_i^{\mathrm {p}} - k_i^p)\frac{{\partial r}}{{\partial t_i}}} \right]\frac{{\partial U_i}}{{\partial x_i}}} \end{array}} \right\} = 0.$$
(20)

We have considered all jurisdictions to be identical. Therefore, Eq. (20) at the symmetric equilibrium can be rewritten as

$$V^\prime X^\prime \left( {1 - \varepsilon } \right) + \frac{{\partial W}}{{\partial U}}\left\{ {\left[ {1 - \varepsilon (1 - \beta )} \right]\frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial G}} - (1 - m)\frac{{\partial U}}{{\partial x}}} \right\} = 0,$$
(21)

where ε is the private capital demand elasticity with respect to the tax rate in jurisdiction i, i.e., \(\varepsilon \equiv - \left( {\frac{{{\mathrm{d}}k_i^{\mathrm {p}}}}{{{\mathrm{d}}t_i}}} \right)\left( {\frac{{t_i}}{{{k}_i^{\mathrm {p}}}}} \right)\forall i\).

As for comparison of Eqs. (8) and (10), comparison of Eqs. (21) and (10) shows the optimal matching grant rate that the central government should choose is given by

$${m} = \frac{{\beta \left( {n - 1} \right) + \varepsilon (1 - \beta )}}{{1 + \beta (n - 1)}} - \frac{{V^\prime X^\prime \left( {1 - \varepsilon } \right)}}{{U_x}}.$$
(22)

We assume that we are on the left side of the Laffer curve, that is, 1 − ε > 0. Recalling once again that V′ < 0, X′ > 0, we know from Eq. (22) that the optimal matching grant rate increases with agency costs even given horizontal fiscal externalities among jurisdictions (∂m/∂VX′ < 0). Notably, this result is an extension of Ogawa (2006) with reference to a particular case.

Next, we derive the relationship between m and ε. Differentiating m with respect to ε, we obtain

$$\frac{{\partial m}}{{\partial \varepsilon }} = \frac{{1 - \beta }}{{1 + \beta \left( {n - 1} \right)}} + \frac{{V^\prime X^\prime }}{{U_x}}.$$
(23)

To study the effects of tax competition and benefit spillovers on the optimal matching grant rate, we present the following basic rationale: Generally, the larger the factors of production demand elasticities with respect to the factor tax rates are, the more intense tax competition becomes. The marginal cost of public funds is widely considered to be larger for local jurisdictions facing a situation of tax competition and benefit spillovers. Therefore, jurisdictional governments are inclined to provide fewer local public goods under such a situation. Consequently, agency costs will decrease because \(V_i^\prime\)[Xi(gi)] < 0 and \(X_i^\prime\)(gi) > 0. However, the welfare of residents will be decreased owing to less provision of local public goods. This means that the utilitarian form of welfare considering agency costs in each jurisdiction significantly depends on the two effects working in the opposite directionFootnote 10. For example, if agency costs and benefit spillovers are smallFootnote 11, the decrease of agency costs is smaller than the decrease of the welfare of residents. The net effect is that the utilitarian form of welfare considering agency costs in each jurisdiction is decreased. Restated, the inefficiency of each jurisdiction is increased. For that reason, the matching grant rate from the central government should be increased to eliminate the inefficiency resulting from tax competition and benefit spillovers. Conversely, if agency costs are large enough, the decrease of those agency costs exceeds the decrease in the welfare of residents. The net effect is an increase in the utilitarian form of welfare considering agency costs in each jurisdiction. The inefficiency of each jurisdiction thus is mitigated. Accordingly, the matching grant rate from the central government should be decreased.

Assuming agency costs are inevitableFootnote 12, we obtain the following proposition:

Proposition We assume that 1 − ε > 0. The following results can be obtained:

  1. (1)

    If agency costs are relatively small, that is, \(1 + \frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}}\, > \,0\), and β = 0, the optimal matching grant rate should increase with the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax.

  2. (2)

    If agency costs are relatively small, that is, \(1 + \frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}}\, > \,0\), and β = 1, the optimal matching grant rate should decrease with the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax.

  3. (3)

    If agency costs are relatively small, that is, \(1 + \frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}}\, > \,0\), and 0 < β < 1, the relationship between the optimal matching grant rate and the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax is ambiguous.

  4. (4)

    If \(\frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}} = - 1\) and β = 0, no relation exists between the optimal matching grant rate and the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax.

  5. (5)

    If \(\frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}} = - 1\) and β > 0, the optimal matching grant rate should decrease with the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax. This is especially so if \(\frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}} = - 1\) and β = 1, \(\frac{{\partial m}}{{\partial \varepsilon }} = - 1\).

  6. (6)

    If agency costs are sufficiently large, that is, \(1 + \frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}}\, < \,0\), the optimal matching grant rate should decrease with the private capital demand elasticities with respect to the capital tax, independent of benefit spillovers.

The above proposition is shown in Table 1.

Table 1 The relationship between m and ε.

For instance, some simulated values for the parameters above can be considered as Table 2.

Table 2 Some simulated values for β, n and \(\frac{{{V}^\prime {X}^\prime }}{{U_x}}\).

Note that horizontal fiscal externalities originating from tax competition and benefit spillovers result in under-provision of local public goods (inefficiency). However, these externalities also can ease the under-provision of local public goods resulting from agency costs (inefficiency correction). These two effects simultaneously work in opposite directions. If agency costs are small and benefit spillover is zero, the former effect exceeds the latter one, meaning horizontal fiscal externalities aggravate the under-provision of local public goods. Conversely, when agency costs are small and benefit spillovers are perfect, or when agency costs are large enough, the latter effect exceeds the former one, which means horizontal fiscal externalities may ease the under-provision of local public goods. In particular, when agency costs are small and benefit spillovers are imperfect, the magnitude of the two effects will be ambiguous. Additionally, when \(\frac{{{V}\prime {X}\prime }}{{U_x}} = - 1\) and benefit spillover is zero, the two effects cancel each other out, which means horizontal fiscal externalities cannot affect the provision of local public goods.

Conclusion

This paper has focused on the effect of horizontal fiscal externalities on the optimal matching grant rate in a model where agency costs are inevitable. When benefit spillover is zero, the relationship between the optimal matching grant rate and private capital demand elasticities with respect to capital tax depends on agency costs. This means that the inefficiency arising from agency costs may be eased by tax competition only if the disutility of effort is so large that the benefits resulting from tax competition exceed its costs when benefit spillover is zero. However, if benefit spillovers occur among jurisdictions, the results will be ambiguous.

Note that the analysis abstracts from dynamic aspects. The ratchet effect is frequently introduced in a two-period setting where timing and commitment of policies (including capital taxes imposed by sub-central governments and matching grants from central government) matter and should also be addressed in future research.

Evidently agency costs (the disutility of effort) in providing local public goods should be set to equal the marginal increase in the probability of re-election multiplied by the value of being re-electedFootnote 13. By ignoring the problems associated with re-election, we obtain some succinct results in our paper. Therefore, the robustness of the results should be further tested by introducing incumbent politicians into the model. In particular, we choose a simple form of social welfare function to formulate the maximisation problem. Therefore, employing a more general form of objective function and considering re-election may provide intriguing insights, an avenue that is left to future research. In addition, our model also needs the verification of empirical analysis in the future research.

Finally, we should more concretely present the policy implications of the above results. Agency costs may aggravate the under-provision of local public goods when no tax competition exists among local jurisdictions. Therefore, the matching grant rate from central government to local governments with relatively large agency costs should be relatively high. Although the matching grant rate increases with agency costs even given horizontal fiscal externalities and benefit spillovers among jurisdictions, the horizontal fiscal externalities among jurisdictions decrease the seriousness of the under-provision of public goods caused by agency costs if agency costs in the political agency process are sufficiently large. Accordingly, the matching grant rate from central government to local governments with relatively large agency costs, ceteris paribus, should be appropriately reduced.